Skip to content
ADVERTISEMENT
Sign In
  • Sections
    • News
    • Advice
    • The Review
  • Topics
    • Data
    • Diversity, Equity, & Inclusion
    • Finance & Operations
    • International
    • Leadership & Governance
    • Teaching & Learning
    • Scholarship & Research
    • Student Success
    • Technology
    • Transitions
    • The Workplace
  • Magazine
    • Current Issue
    • Special Issues
    • Podcast: College Matters from The Chronicle
  • Newsletters
  • Virtual Events
  • Ask Chron
  • Store
    • Featured Products
    • Reports
    • Data
    • Collections
    • Back Issues
  • Jobs
    • Find a Job
    • Post a Job
    • Professional Development
    • Career Resources
    • Virtual Career Fair
  • More
  • Sections
    • News
    • Advice
    • The Review
  • Topics
    • Data
    • Diversity, Equity, & Inclusion
    • Finance & Operations
    • International
    • Leadership & Governance
    • Teaching & Learning
    • Scholarship & Research
    • Student Success
    • Technology
    • Transitions
    • The Workplace
  • Magazine
    • Current Issue
    • Special Issues
    • Podcast: College Matters from The Chronicle
  • Newsletters
  • Virtual Events
  • Ask Chron
  • Store
    • Featured Products
    • Reports
    • Data
    • Collections
    • Back Issues
  • Jobs
    • Find a Job
    • Post a Job
    • Professional Development
    • Career Resources
    • Virtual Career Fair
    Upcoming Events:
    An AI-Driven Work Force
    AI and Microcredentials
Sign In
Blog Logo

Percolator

Research that matters.

To the Trickster Go the Spoils

By Tom Bartlett September 18, 2012

William H. Press had been messing around with the Prisoner’s Dilemma, the classic game-theory conundrum, as a sort of side project. That is apparently what you do in your spare time when you’re a computer scientist and computational biologist at the University of Texas at Austin, not to mention president of the American Association for the Advancement of Science. Press wrote a computer program to assist in this happy diversion, but it kept crashing and he couldn’t figure out why.

To continue reading for FREE, please sign in.

Sign In

Or subscribe now to read with unlimited access for as low as $10/month.

Don’t have an account? Sign up now.

A free account provides you access to a limited number of free articles each month, plus newsletters, job postings, salary data, and exclusive store discounts.

Sign Up

William H. Press had been messing around with the Prisoner’s Dilemma, the classic game-theory conundrum, as a sort of side project. That is apparently what you do in your spare time when you’re a computer scientist and computational biologist at the University of Texas at Austin, not to mention president of the American Association for the Advancement of Science. Press wrote a computer program to assist in this happy diversion, but it kept crashing and he couldn’t figure out why.

He was still mulling it when he ran into Freeman J. Dyson at a conference. Dyson, who is 88, is a professor emeritus of physics at the Institute for Advanced Study, in Princeton, N.J., a renowned mathematician, and the author of a number of popular books, including Disturbing the Universe. In 1951 Dyson was given a professorship at Cornell even though he lacked a doctorate. Press was tenured at Harvard while in his twenties. They make quite a pair.

William Press
William Press

Press explained to Dyson what he’d been up to, and Dyson, intrigued, promised to give it some thought. Dyson has described himself as “quite ignorant” about the details of the dilemma before Press talked to him about it. A couple of days later, Dyson sent Press an e-mail that said in part: “Thank you for this problem, which kept me busy over the weekend.”

ADVERTISEMENT

Along with the note, there were some formulas. When Press examined them, he was elated. He wrote back that Dyson’s calculations were “truly wonderful.” Dyson hadn’t actually answered the more minor question that first interested Press; instead he had discovered a wildly successful, and apparently new, approach to a well-worn scenario. Says Press: “The joy of collaborating with Freeman is that, once he gives you the answer, you can work out that it’s obvious, but you never could have seen it for yourself.”

That answer is, according to some, “amazing,” “undoubtedly a breakthrough.” Because of it, “the world of game theory is currently on fire.” Or, say others, it’s a more modest accomplishment—important for sure, but not responsible for any infernos. Or maybe it’s not so wonderful after all.

So why does this matter, except to the tiny subset of the population that spends weekends doing math? It matters because the Prisoner’s Dilemma is thought to have a wide range of applications. In biology, for instance, it may help provide models for the evolution of cooperation. It’s also thought to apply to foreign-policy situations like two countries’ acquiring nuclear stockpiles. (If both countries agree to disarm, they can spend their resources elsewhere. Everyone wins. But if one country disarms, and the other doesn’t, the latter country can nuke with impunity.)

First, some background.

One way to get a sense of the Prisoner’s Dilemma is to watch the British game show Golden Balls. In the show’s final round, each of the two contestants is presented with a choice: “split or steal.” If both choose to split, each walks home with half of the prize money. If both choose to steal, each walks away with nothing. If one steals and the other splits, then the stealer walks away with all of the prize money. Neither knows what the other has chosen until after they’ve made their own choices.

ADVERTISEMENT

The upshot, just as in the classic version involving two prisoners locked in separate cells, is that cooperation pays, but sometimes selfishness can pay even more.

In 1978 and 1979, Robert M. Axelrod, a political scientist at the University of Michigan at Ann Arbor, ran a tournament to discover which strategies were the most effective at the so-called Iterated Prisoner’s Dilemma—that is, playing the game not just once, but dozens or even hundreds of times in row. Is it best never to cooperate? Or always? Can you outsmart your opponent, cooperating at first, then defecting once you’ve established trust? Unlike Golden Balls, there was no prize money or bald, grinning host in Axelrod’s contest. The outcome was determined by a computer program.

Axelrod found that a strategy called “Tit for Tat” usually emerges victorious. If you’re playing Tit for Tat, you always mirror your opponent’s choices. If your opponent cooperated the first time, you cooperate the next. If your opponent doesn’t cooperate, neither do you. If your opponent starts cooperating again, you follow suit. Ever since then, for three-plus decades, it’s been widely accepted that Tit for Tat is the way to go.

What Dyson and Press came up with are several mathematical strategies that, according to a paper they wrote, actually outperform Tit for Tat. The strategy long touted as unbeatable may be more vulnerable than previously thought.

The new strategies, called Zero Determinant, are like a sophisticated coin flip. If the opponent cooperated in the previous turn, the computer runs a formula to decide what to do next. If the opponent didn’t cooperate, it runs a different formula. The program doesn’t pay attention to the history of choices nor does it have any theory of the opponent’s mind. It’s a formula based only on the previous decision. But playing against a dumb opponent—one who is just trying to do the best he or she can—the formulas regularly rise to the top. “I don’t think there’s a deep explanation,” says Press, when asked how the formulas work. “I think it’s a little tweak buried in the math.”

UNITED STATES - MARCH 22:  Physicist Freeman J. Dyson, winner of the 2000 Templeton Prize for Progress in Religion, at The Church Center for the United Nations in New York, where the announcement was made.  (Jon Naso, NY Daily News Archive, Getty Images)
Freeman DysonNew York Daily News Archive

One blogger has developed an online simulator that uses the formulas and allows you to play the role of the dumb opponent. When you’re playing against those strategies, the computer’s choices feel random: Sometimes it cooperates, sometimes it doesn’t. There doesn’t seem to be a pattern. And yet, when I played it, the computer’s score consistently beat mine. It was kind of dispiriting, like being out-evolved.

ADVERTISEMENT

I asked William Poundstone, who wrote a 1993 book titled Prisoner’s Dilemma that explores the problem’s history and implications, what he thought of the paper. “I was really surprised,” he says. “This challenges how we think about the dilemma.” What it shows, according to Poundstone, is that “if you’re a super-smart player, you can have the upper hand in the game.”

One very general way to look at it is that before, with Tit for Tat, the moral of the story was that cooperation is best for everyone involved. Kindness triumphs. Now it’s to the trickster go the spoils.

Press chuckles at statements like that. People love to search for a human narrative in the cold numbers. Press agrees with a blog post on the n-Category Café by Michael Shulman, a postdoctoral fellow in mathematics at the University of California at San Diego, in which he deems such statements overly simplistic and over the top. That said, Shulman writes that the new strategies are a “discovery of the first order” with “fascinating implications.”

Axelrod is less impressed. The Michigan professor, whose computer tournaments and 1984 book The Evolution of Cooperation are touchstones among those who study the dilemma, says similar approaches (including one with the foreboding title “Grim’s Trigger”) have been tried before but have proved unsuccessful.He writes in an e-mail that Press and Dyson “haven’t really come up with a way to ‘beat’ Tit for Tat.” But Press seems to differ: “We’re about 25 years too late to the party,” he says, referring to Axelrod’s tournament, “but perhaps if we had been there, we would have won.”

Axelrod’s criticism is an outlier among the accolades, though the merits of the new strategies are likely to be discussed for years to come, just as Axelrod’s tournament results have been pored over since the Carter administration. Which goes to show that even a problem that’s been studied to death may yet have some life left in it.

We welcome your thoughts and questions about this article. Please email the editors or submit a letter for publication.
Share
  • Twitter
  • LinkedIn
  • Facebook
  • Email
About the Author
Tom Bartlett
Tom Bartlett is a senior writer who covers science and ideas. Follow him on Twitter @tebartl.
ADVERTISEMENT
ADVERTISEMENT

More News

Photo illustration showing Santa Ono seated, places small in the corner of a dark space
'Unrelentingly Sad'
Santa Ono Wanted a Presidency. He Became a Pariah.
Illustration of a rushing crowd carrying HSI letters
Seeking precedent
Funding for Hispanic-Serving Institutions Is Discriminatory and Unconstitutional, Lawsuit Argues
Photo-based illustration of scissors cutting through paper that is a photo of an idyllic liberal arts college campus on one side and money on the other
Finance
Small Colleges Are Banding Together Against a Higher Endowment Tax. This Is Why.
Pano Kanelos, founding president of the U. of Austin.
Q&A
One Year In, What Has ‘the Anti-Harvard’ University Accomplished?

From The Review

Photo- and type-based illustration depicting the acronym AAUP with the second A as the arrow of a compass and facing not north but southeast.
The Review | Essay
The Unraveling of the AAUP
By Matthew W. Finkin
Photo-based illustration of the Capitol building dome propped on a stick attached to a string, like a trap.
The Review | Opinion
Colleges Can’t Trust the Federal Government. What Now?
By Brian Rosenberg
Illustration of an unequal sign in black on a white background
The Review | Essay
What Is Replacing DEI? Racism.
By Richard Amesbury

Upcoming Events

Plain_Acuity_DurableSkills_VF.png
Why Employers Value ‘Durable’ Skills
Warwick_Leadership_Javi.png
University Transformation: a Global Leadership Perspective
  • Explore Content
    • Latest News
    • Newsletters
    • Letters
    • Free Reports and Guides
    • Professional Development
    • Virtual Events
    • Chronicle Store
    • Chronicle Intelligence
    • Jobs in Higher Education
    • Post a Job
  • Know The Chronicle
    • About Us
    • Vision, Mission, Values
    • DEI at The Chronicle
    • Write for Us
    • Work at The Chronicle
    • Our Reporting Process
    • Advertise With Us
    • Brand Studio
    • Accessibility Statement
  • Account and Access
    • Manage Your Account
    • Manage Newsletters
    • Individual Subscriptions
    • Group and Institutional Access
    • Subscription & Account FAQ
  • Get Support
    • Contact Us
    • Reprints & Permissions
    • User Agreement
    • Terms and Conditions
    • Privacy Policy
    • California Privacy Policy
    • Do Not Sell My Personal Information
1255 23rd Street, N.W. Washington, D.C. 20037
© 2025 The Chronicle of Higher Education
The Chronicle of Higher Education is academe’s most trusted resource for independent journalism, career development, and forward-looking intelligence. Our readers lead, teach, learn, and innovate with insights from The Chronicle.
Follow Us
  • twitter
  • instagram
  • youtube
  • facebook
  • linkedin